Monopoly

Revision as of 16:43, 28 July 2017 by Jmdonev (talk | contribs)

A firm that is the only supplier or seller in a market is said to have a monopoly. The lack of competition means the firm can charge a much higher price for goods and services because they don't have any competition.[1] In a perfectly competitive market, sellers are price takers meaning they are unable to charge the price of the good or service that they want. In a monopoly scenario, the single seller is able to set the price because they do not have to compete with firms offering lower prices. A firm that is able to change the price of the good or service it sells has market power.[2]

As an example, imagine one goes to purchase gasoline for their vehicle and there is only one firm that owns all the gasoline stations in the city. The price of gasoline is closely linked to the price of oil, normally as the price of oil falls so does the price of gasoline. However, in a market with only one supplier of gasoline, the firm could keep the price of gasoline artificially high even if there is a fall in the price of oil. The business can do this because no one is selling gasoline at a lower price.

Monopolistic Effect on a Market

Figure 1. Monopolies disrupt the equilibrium when the competition is disrupted, Point A → Point B. There is less of the good (like gasoline) and it is more expensive (people are paying more at the gas station). Both the consumer and producer experience some inefficiency. The portion of the red triangle above the dotted line is the amount of inefficiency the consumers experience. The portion below is the amount of inefficiency experienced by the producer.[3]

Monopolies create problems because there is no competition to ensure the proper price and quantity. The market becomes inefficient as the good or service is both more expensive and less available. Figure 1 shows what this looks like graphically:

  • At Point A the market is at equilibrium, it is competitive and the supply (S) meets the demand (D). Both the price (PC) and the quantity (QC) reflect this equilibrium.
  • At Point B there is a monopolistic market where one seller controls the market, the single seller is able to both restrict the quantity available QM from and raise the price PM
  • The inefficiency in the market as a result of a monopoly is represented by the red triangle in Figure 1. Because the equilibrium is disrupted, both consumers and the producer suffer. This is called deadweight loss and occurs in a monopolistic market as a result of the restricted supply.

In this scenario, some people who want the good are not able to get it. Those who are able to get the good have to pay a higher price. If this is not corrected of regulated, it could lead to a market failure.

Depending on what good is in this market the effects can be minor or major. If it is a luxury good such as a sports car or a handbag then the effects are relatively minor, the market is not efficient but it will not have a large social cost. Conversely, if the good is deemed to be an essential good (like gasoline, or the ability to heat a home) then the effect of an inefficient market can be devastating.

Why Efficiency is Important

An essential good such as food or electricity can have a major social cost when the market for these goods is inefficient. If the price for food or electricity is so high that a portion of the population cannot afford it than this can translate into a large social cost.

Today, in many places electricity can be considered an essential good, or a need. In a society with a geographic position that experiences a cold winter or season, being unable to afford electricity can lead to a consumer having to make a decision that could be harmful. If a home in a developing nation was powered by a modular electric heater and the price of electricity rises so high that it is unaffordable the household will have to find an alternative. Perhaps the household decided to burn wood because the cost of a natural gas heater is too expensive. The burning of wood for heat or charcoal for cooking means that the people of the house hold will be exposed to harmful effects from the smoke emitted. The use of wood, charcoal and other solid fuels increases the instances of pneumonia, stroke, heart disease, and lung cancer.[4] The increased instances of these ailments can burden a healthcare system and make that system inefficient as a result. While inefficient markets are not inherently a bad thing and in some situations can be a positive outcome, there are scenarios where inefficient markets can have drastic effects and impose a large social cost.

Natural Monopoly

A natural monopoly emerges when it is more efficient for one firm to produce a good or service than multiple firms.[5] Common examples of this are the distribution of water and electricity in a municipality. The cost of building the infrastructure for both water and electricity is so expensive that it is much more efficient for one firm to supply the market. Natural monopolies emerge as a result of the economies of scale available in the market, meaning it is easier for a larger firm to produce at a lower cost than it is for smaller firms to do so.[6]

Suppose three firms, one small, one medium and one large, were competing in the market for the distribution of electricity in a city. The large firm builds its infrastructure throughout the city and can offer electricity at a low rate to consumers. The medium sized firm also builds its infrastructure alongside that of the larger firm but because of the smaller size of the firm it has to charge higher prices to recoup the cost of the infrastructure quicker. The small firm decides not to enter the market because the infrastructure that is required is too expensive for them to build and their rates would be far too high making them uncompetitive in the market. In this case, the high cost that prevented the small firm form entering the market is called a barrier to entry. Eventually the medium sized firm will fall out of the market due to the nature of utilities where the lowest price prevails. Because the other two firms left (or didn't enter) the market "naturally", the larger firm is left as the sole producer and therefore it is a natural monopoly.

Is There a More Efficient Way?

There are some criticisms of natural monopolies as efficient outcomes, the most prominent being that because a monopoly does not have competition it will operate at a higher cost. If there was competition the firm would be forced to minimize costs as much as possible in order to present consumers with the most competitive price. There are three main reasons for these inefficiencies:[7]

  1. Technology- A monopolistic firm will be less likely to make their production more efficient because they do not have to compete with firms that do have more efficient schemes, they do not have to optimize their production.
  2. Management- A monopolistic firm has a management scheme that is less likely to seek efficient solutions to problems and is less likely to take risks. This is simply because they do not have to. A competitive firm has to do both of those things in order to get an edge on its other competitors in the market.
  3. Innovation- A monopolistic firm is less likely to innovate, this is an overarching reason for the inefficiency of a monopoly. Because there is no incentive to maximize (i.e. the need to stay ahead of other firms), a monopoly is less likely to invest in new technologies, production methods, management teams and other factors.

References

  1. J.Black, N. Hashimzade, and G. Myles. (2009) "Monopoly." [Online], Available: http://www.oxfordreference.com/view/10.1093/acref/9780199237043.001.0001/acref-9780199237043-e-2026?rskey=eK2AMW&result=1 , 2009 [May 27, 2016]
  2. A. Goolsbee, S. Levitt and C. Syverson. ‘’Microeconomics’’. New York: Worth Publishers, 2013, pp. 348.
  3. Created internally by a member of the Energy Education team.
  4. The World Health Organization. (May 7, 2015). Household Air Pollution [Online]. Available: http://www.who.int/mediacentre/factsheets/fs292/en/ Overall, the World Health Organization estimates that there are 4 million deaths per year that are partially caused by the use of solid fuels, including charcoal.
  5. The Economist. "Natural Monopoly." [Online], Available: http://www.economist.com/economics-a-to-z/n#node-21529735 [May 27, 2016].
  6. C. Decker. Modern Economic Regulation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2015, pp. 18.
  7. C. Decker. Modern Economic Regulation. pp. 25.